This week
- Revenue-maximizing DSIC auctions
- completely different goal than social welfare maximization
- average-case analysis
Review
Spectrum auction's problem: VERY LOW REVENUE
Social welfare maximization
many applications
makes sense even in cases where revenue maximization seems to be more important (e.g. keeping customers compared to competitors)
educational value: ideal auctions and ideal mechanisms always exist
Single item auction with a single potential buyer
revenue?
what other truthful auctions exist?
posted prices, take it or leave it offers
is it possible to maximize revenue without knowledge of private valuations?
for example, a fixed price of 10 work fine for valuations higher than 10 while it will be disastrous for smaller prices.
Revenue maximization
Average case analysis
single-parameter environment
Independent random variables representing valuations with distributions \(F_1,F_2,\cdots,F_n\) with continuous probability density functions \(f_1,f_2,\cdots,f_n\), defined in \([0,+\infty)\)
participant \(i\) selects random valuation from distribution \(F_i\).
crucial assumption: the mechanism designer knows the distributions of valuations $$ F_i(z)=\Pr[v_i\le z]=\int_0^zf_i(x)\mathrm dx $$
the potential buyer has a random valuation, drawn from a known probability distribution \(F\).
Fixed price \(r\)
What is the best choice of \(r\)? $$ \mathbb E(Revenue)=r\times(1-F(r)) $$
Two potential buyers in revenue maximization
assume \(F\) is uniform distribution in \([0,1]\)
what's the revenue of the second-price auction?
i.e. smallest valuation among the two.
- the highest bid wins the item if it is higher than the reserve price \(r\)
- pays the maximum between the lowest bid and \(r\)
what do we gain?
Better revenue in cases of very small lowest bid.
what do we loose?
The item is not always sold.
for revenue:
maximized for \(r=\frac{1}{2}\) at the value \(\frac{5}{12}\).
Revenue-optimal auctions
participant \(i\) selects random valuation from distribution \(F_i\).
probability distributions \(\mathbf F\) with continuous probability density function \(\mathbf f\). defined in \([0,+\infty)\)
Assumption
- the mechanism designer knows the distributions of valuations.
- the valuations of different potential buyers are independent
virtual valuations: \(\phi_i(v_i)=v_i-\frac{1-F_i(v_i)}{f_i(v_i)}\)
here \(v_i\) stands for desired revenue, \(\frac{1-F_i(v_i)}{f_i(v_i)}\) stands for discount.
Revenue and virtual valuation
Lemma: for every single-parameter environment with \(n\) participant having independent valuations drawn from distribution \(\mathbf F\). every DSIC mechanism \((\mathbf x,\mathbf p)\), every participant \(i\) and every vector \(\mathbf v_{-i}\) of valuations $$ \mathbb E_{v_i\sim F_i}[p_i(\mathbf v)]=\mathbb E_{v_i\sim F_i}[\varphi_i(v_i)\cdot x_i(\mathbf v)] $$ theorem: expected revenue=expected virtual valuations $$ \mathbb E_{\mathbf v\sim\mathbf F}[\sum_{i=1}^np_i(\mathbf v)]=\mathbb E_{\mathbf v\sim\mathbf F}[\sum_{i=1}^n\varphi_i(v_i)\cdot x_i(\mathbf v)] $$ proof using the lemma above and linearity of expectation.
Proof of the lemma
Revenue-optimal auction design
new goal: select an allocation rule that maximizes the virtual social welfare $$ \mathbb E_{\mathbf v\sim\mathbf F}[\sum_{i=1}^n\varphi_i(v_i)\cdot x_i(\mathbf v)] $$ we restrict ourselves to regular distributions that have the property that the virtual valuation function \(\varphi_i(v_i)=v_i-\frac{1-F_i(v_i)}{f_i(v_i)}\) is non-decreasing
then, the allocation rule that maximizes the virtual social welfare is monotone.
process: \(n\) potential buyer with regular distributions
- compute the virtual valuation \(\phi_i(v_i)\) of the truthfully reported valuation \(v_i\).
- select the feasible allocation that maximizes the virtual social welfare \(\sum_{i=1}^n\varphi_i(v_i)x_i(\mathbf v)\)
- charge payments according to Myerson's lemma